Tuesday, October 9, 2012

Private Property, the High Modernist State, and the Bidoon


Barro argues that the government should guarantee property rights. These property rights are essential to securing stable income, drawing productive investments, and providing incentives to pursue long-term policies. By protecting property rights, governments can help to make their countries friendlier to growth. Yet, it might be that the people don’t need the government to codify property rights but rather the government needs codified property rights to govern the people.
The solidification of property rights by the state requires the legibility of such rules. States require solid property rights in order to achieve taxation schemes; a government needs to know how much people have in order to take it away from them. In James C. Scott’s 1998 book, Seeing Like A State, he explains that in traditional societies property rights and regulations were determined at the village level. Thus, there could be serious discrepancies between villages in the type of system used. While to the people living in each village this system would be completely comprehensible, it would be a nightmare for state officials. It is much easier to measure property and thereby taxation when the property is divided into grid-like land, owned by only one owner, who harvests only one crop. For example, in Norway, the land of large farms, called “Gards” were owned communally, yet families had property rights to portions of the yield. These villagers also shared commons resources such as forests, fisheries, and resin collection. Although there was no convincing evidence that this common property system was less productive, the state forced the solidification of property rights. Thus, it seems that the idea of a modern state necessitates a comprehensible property system. The role of government in the traditional conception of property rights is not necessarily based in concern over the wellbeing of the people.
Furthermore, while people with property rights clearly benefit from strong property rights systems, there is an equity concern. The process of guaranteeing property rights may leave some out. In the solidification of property rights, the complexities of older systems of ownership may be overlooked, making some worse off.
For example, in the mid-twentieth century, the fall of the Ottoman Empire and the corresponding rise of the nation-state in the Persian Gulf led to the creation of new borders. These states delineated their borders, identified their population, and codified property rights. However, for thousands of years, nomadic tribes had maintained rights to access to lands and water sources. When property rights were laid down, according to state-centric conceptions of ownership that are biased towards sedentary groups (because they are more comprehensible), nomadic tribes were left out. Many of these people were not even given the right to a nationality. These people, known as the bedoon, meaning “without” in Arabic, are a significant minority. In Kuwait alone, which has a population of 1.3 million people, between 80,000 and 140,000 people are without citizenship, according to Refugees International. These people, deprived of their property rights by a state trying to solidify property rights, cannot easily get marriage licenses, birth or death certificates. Thus, they cannot legally get married, own property, or find employment within the formal sector. Many bidun support themselves through underground economic activity such as peddling goods on the street, hawking DVDS, and in some cases even selling blood and organs. The bidun are barred from registering a vehicle, telephone line, or buy a SIM card.
While property rights do have benefits and are critical to a developing society, governments wishing to implement them more strongly should make sure that they are doing it for the right reason and not oversimplifying the existing system of property rights.

No comments:

Post a Comment