One of the first things I noticed when reading the Worldly
Philosophers was the intense, perhaps excessive, detail with which Heilbroner
describes both the personal lives and qualities of the great economic thinkers
as well as the historical context in which they lived. At first, this level of
description confused me slightly. In my prior studies of economics, texts have
always focused on the ideas of thinkers, rather than their lives, histories and
quirks. Approaching economics as a “science”, this makes a certain degree of
sense. If economics truly is a science in the sense that, say, physics is, then
we should not care much for the history of those who discover its laws or the
societies in which they lived. Information like Karl Marx’s marital
infidelities with his unpaid maid or Adam Smith’s strange walking patterns and
intense periods of absentmindedness may be interesting to the trivia buff, but
how much they can tell us about economic thought – its content, direction, and
so forth – is at the least doubtful.
Yet at the same time, Heilbroner’s descriptions,
particularly of the political and historical context for the birth of major
economic ideas, shows a significant way in which economics diverges from
traditional, hard sciences. Given the information Heilbroner presents, it would
seem that at different points in history since the birth of capitalism,
different theories have greater explanatory and predictive power than others.
For example, Ricardo’s concern about landlords and rent may have been
incredibly relevant to the society in which he existed; however, in the modern
United States, where we currently pay farmers not to farm, such concerns about agricultural
landowners reaping all the benefit in our economy seem fairly moot. Similarly,
Marx’s concern about the business cycle may not have made any sense to people of
Smith’s time; nor would his ominous predictions hold much credence after World
War II and the recovery from the Great Depression, particularly in the United
States where increasingly painful business cycles all but disappeared (at least
through the 1950s and 1960s).
Because economics seems to differ so drastically from other sciences in this way, one wonders how much economics truly can offer in terms of predictive power. Another crucial question is how much we can develop an understanding of economic thought that will remain relevant in the very long run, given that economics studies individuals and societies, both of which are inclined to undergo massive changes over time. I do not doubt the potential for intelligent, well-constructed theories, ideas and models to provide insight for shorter periods of time (which, as in the case of Keynes and his warnings against the flaws of the Versailles Treaty, may mean decades). However, it seems doubtful that even the brightest thinkers of any age could predict the functions of an economy belonging to an era that is otherwise unfathomable to them. Without any possible understanding of the culture and historical context of a society, they cannot know the economic axioms or “constants” of that society and cannot develop a proper theory based upon them. Perhaps if determinism is correct and we reach adequately “scientific” understanding of politics, culture, and other social phenomena, we will be able to accurately model economic growth several centuries into the future. If that potential exists, we certainly have not yet reached it. At the least, it seems that until we can reach such a point, economics is a study that must necessarily question and review its central precepts for accuracy if it wishes to stay relevant and informative simply because it depends so heavily upon the historical context and the society within which it operates.
No comments:
Post a Comment